Effectiveness of community health financing in meeting the cost of illness*
Alexander S. Preker,1 Guy Carrin,2 David Dror,3 Melitta Jakab,4 William Hsiao,5 & Dyna Arhin-Tenkorang6
ABSTRACT: How to finance and provide health care for the more than 1.3 billion rural poor and informal sector workers in low- and middle-income countries is one of the greatest challenges facing the international development community. This article presents the main findings from an extensive survey of the literature of community financing arrangements, and selected experiences from the Asia and Africa regions. Most community financing schemes have evolved in the context of severe economic constraints, political instability, and lack of good governance. Micro-level household data analysis indicates that community financing improves access by rural and informal sector workers to needed heath care and provides them with some financial protection against the cost of illness. Macro-level cross-country analysis gives empirical support to the hypothesis that risk-sharing in health financing matters in terms of its impact on both the level and distribution of health, financial fairness and responsiveness indicators.
The background research done for this article points to five key policies available to governments to improve the effectiveness and sustainability of existing community financing schemes. This includes: (a) increased and well-targeted subsidies to pay for the premiums of low-income populations; (b) insurance to protect against expenditure fluctuations and re-insurance to enlarge the effective size of small risk pools; (c) effective prevention and case management techniques to limit expenditure fluctuations; (d) technical support to strengthen the management capacity of local schemes; and (e) establishment and strengthening of links with the formal financing and provider networks.
Keywords Community health services/economics ;Financing, Health; Consumer participation/economics; Households; Cost of illness; Developing countries; Multicenter studies (source: MeSH, NLM).
Mots clés Service public santé/économie; Financement, Santé; Participation consommateurs/économie; Coût maladie; Ménages; Pays en développement; Etude multicentrique (source: MeSH, INSERM).
Palabras clave Servicios de salud comunitaria/ economía; Financiamiento de la salud; Participación comunitaria/economía; costo de las enfermedades; Hogares; Países en desarrollo; Estudios multicéntricos (fuente: DeCS, BIREME).
Bulletin of the World Health Organization 2002;80:143-150.
Introduction
One of the world's most urgent problems is financing and providing health care for the 1.3 billion poor people who live in low- and middle-income countries. Many poor people lack access to effective and affordable drugs and to surgery and other interventions, largely because of weaknesses in the financing and delivery of health care (13).Although 93% of the global burden of disease falls on 84% of the world's poor, only 11% of global health spending (US$ 2800 billion) occurs in low- and middle-income countries.
For years, many low- and middle-income countries have tried to leapfrog the developmental process needed to expand risk protection to universal coverage. The preferred mechanism for this has been to design and implement traditional public financing instruments, such as general revenues and social insurance. Few have succeeded in this approach. Estimates of the expenditure gap to achieving universal access to health services at low income levels through such public financing mechanisms range from US$ 2550 billion (4) to over US$ 100 billion (5). In this context, community financing, notwithstanding its shortcomings, is often the only viable option for providing some financial protection and access to basic health services for the poor (6).
This paper summarizes the results of a large-scale collaborative study that aimed at assessing the impact, strengths and weaknesses of community involvement in financial protection against the cost of illness and at improving access to health care for poor rural populations and workers in the informal sector (7). It explores potential policies for tackling managerial, organizational and institutional weaknesses in community financing, rather than trying to replace them with direct government intervention, which has often proved unsuccessful.
Differences between rich and poor in financial protection against cost of illness
A combination of general taxation, social insurance, private health insurance and limited out-of-pocket user charges has become the preferred instrument for health financing in middle- and higher-income countries (8). In these contexts, large segments of the population work in urban settings and in formal employment. It is relatively easy to tax such workers at source and to design health care systems that are financed by government or payroll taxes.
The policy options for financing health care at low income levels are, however, more restricted. Low-income countries often have large populations in the rural and informal sectors, which limits the effective taxation capacity of their governments. In middle-income and upper-income countries, large segments of the population work in urban settings and the formal employment sectors, and it is relatively easy to tax workers at source and design health care systems financed by government or payroll taxes. In most low-income countries the formal urban employment sector is small relative to the populations in rural areas and in informal employment. In these countries, such populations often have no effective collective arrangements whereby they can pay for health care or obtain protection from the cost of illness (912).
A related set of problems occurs during the pooling stage of health financing. Pooling requires some transfer of resources from rich to poor, from healthy people to sick people, and from the gainfully employed to the economically inactive. Without such pooling, people on low incomes are exposed to serious financial hardship when they fall ill. Where pooling exists it is often fragmented along income groups, preventing effective cross-subsidies between the higher and lower income groups. Cross-subsidies may also be prevented when fragmentation is based on professional categories, e.g. there may be separate pools for workers and farmers in the same region. Many households become destitute when faced with severe illness that leads to admission to hospital (13). The proportion of the population covered by risk-sharing arrangements is comparatively low at low income levels (Fig. 1).
Faced with overwhelming demand and very limited resources, many governments find it difficult to ration health care so that public expenditure is targeted on the poor. In many low-income countries the rich often benefit more than the poor from public subsidies and public expenditure (14). Public policies that, in theory, offer health care to the whole population may unwittingly shunt scarce health care resources away from the poor and towards segments of the population with more political influence over the health care system (15).
Role of communities
Discouraged by the inability of governments to reach rural populations and people engaged in the informal sector, communities have increasingly been mobilizing themselves to secure financial protection against the cost of illness for excluded population groups (1620). A range of health financing instruments has emerged over the past decade, including microinsurance, community health funds, mutual health organizations, rural health insurance, revolving drugs funds, and community involvement in user-fee management. Their common feature is the active involvement of the community in revenue collection, pooling, resource allocation and, frequently, service provision.
Three relatively recent contributions from development practice and thinking have provided inspiration for community financing initiatives (Table 1) (21): microfinance instruments, i.e. microcredits, microsavings, microinsurance and financial intermediation, have succeeded in reaching the poor where traditional poverty alleviation instruments have failed; there has been an increasing awareness of the links between social capital, i.e. community, network, institutional and societal links, and a range of development outcomes; there is new evidence from mainstream theories on welfare economics, public finance, health economics and public health as to the impact of traditional instruments on poverty alleviation.
Links to microfinance organizations
The role of microfinance in poverty alleviation for low-income groups has received considerable attention in recent years (2225). Until recently, few financial and risk-protection mechanisms were accessible to the poor. It was assumed that people living on less than US$ 1 a day were neither willing nor able to save or to contribute to insurance against the risks they faced. The poor were described as unbankable and uninsurable (24). The following microfinance instruments have been developed with a view to improving the financial stability and productivity of low-income households: microcredits that help to improve immediate human, physical and social capital, e.g. small short-term loans that help to pay for training, farm equipment or access to social networks; savings for building up medium-term capital, such as education, down payments on land, and dowries for the marriage of daughters into good families; insurance to meet unpredictable expenses (such as theft, loss and illness); and financial intermediation, i.e. payment systems that facilitate trade and investment.
Although most progress has been made in microcredits and microsavings, the extension of risk management techniques from other sectors to the health sector is now happening in many microfinance and development organizations in low- income countries. This is especially true in the case of microinsurance (23, 26). Reinsurance has been considered as a means of tackling some of the inherent problems of the smaller size of the risk pool associated with these schemes (27).
Links to social capital at community level
When hard times strike, family and friends are often the ultimate safety net for low-income groups. Social capital can be conceptualized in the following dimensions, which have the potential for both positive and negative impacts on development: community links, such as extended families, local organizations, clubs, associations and civic groups, i.e. people in small communities, helping each other; network links between similar communities (horizontal) and between different communities (vertical), such as ethnic groups, religious groups, class structures, the sexes, and so on; institutional links, for instance through the political, legal and cultural environments of communities; and societal links between governments and their citizens through complementarity and embeddedness, e.g. publicprivate partnerships and the legal framework that protects the rights of association (such as chambers of commerce and business groups), and community participation in public organizations (e.g. community members on city councils and hospital boards).
But such social capital has both benefits and costs. A disadvantage arises when communities and networks become isolated, parochial, or at cross-purposes with society's collective interests, such as ghettos, gangs or cartels. Intercommunity ties or bridges are needed to overcome the tendency of communities and networks to pursue narrow sectarian interests. Some of these shortcomings can affect community financing schemes.
Schemes that share risk only among the poor deprive their members of much-needed cross-subsidies from higher income groups.
Schemes that remain isolated and small deprive their members of the benefits of spreading risks across a broader population.
Schemes that are disconnected from the broader referral system and health networks deprive their members of the more comprehensive range of care available through the formal health care system.
Links to mainstream public economics
In addition to their links to microfinance and social capital, community-financing schemes benefit from their connections with the overall welfare of the society in which they operate, with the system of public financing, no matter how weak it may be, and with the broader social policy underpinning the prevailing national health system. Schemes that build such connections at an early stage are better able to evolve in terms of expanding the number of members covered, the level of resources mobilized, the size of the risk pool, and the range of benefits they can offer. Their members have more to gain through such connectivity than they would through isolation.
Proponents of stronger links between community involvement and public finance argue their case on both philosophical and technical grounds. There have been many examples of failure to secure objectives of efficiency (2832) and equity (33, 34) by the private sector and market forces acting alone.
Assessment of impact, strengths and weaknesses
Past reviews of community financing have been largely descriptive, using macro-level country data. Only recently have authors begun to consider the impact of community-based financing mechanisms at the household level (35). We have used a combination of these techniques. The following levels of analysis were included in order to assess the impact, strengths, and weaknesses of community involvement in financial protection against the cost of illness and in health improvement (Table 2): a survey of the literature on the impact, strengths and weakness of different types of community involvement in health financing (20); regional reviews of Asian and African experiences of community involvement in health care financing (36, 37); micro-level analysis of household data concerning the specific impact of community financing schemes on the overall welfare of the poor (financial protection and access to health services for the poor) (35); and macro- level cross-country analysis of the impact of different health care financing on performance indicators in national health systems (health, financial fairness, responsiveness) (38).
Discussion
"Community financing" has become a generic expression covering a large variety of health financing arrangements (26, 3941). Different authors use the term in different ways (16, 17, 36, 42). Microinsurance, community health funds, mutual health organizations, rural health insurance, revolving drugs funds, and community involvement in user-fee management have all been referred to as community-based financing. Our review covered the entire range of health financing instruments where the community was involved in securing financial protection against the cost of illness and in providing access to priority health services.
Literature survey
We conducted a literature survey based on 45 published and unpublished reports and conference proceedings completed after 1990. The aim was to synthesize the impact of community financing as reported by others in the following three dimensions.
How successful are community financing schemes in mobilizing resources for health care?
How successful are they in providing financial protection for their members against the costs of illness?
How successful are they in including the poor?
Resource mobilization
The literature provides good evidence that community financing arrangements make a positive contribution to the financing of health care at low income levels. In doing so, such arrangements improve people's access to drugs, primary care, and even to more advanced hospital care (43). This community involvement allows rural and low-income populations to raise more resources with which to pay for health care than would otherwise have been possible (41, 44, 45). But there are great variations in the ability of various schemes to raise the money needed to pay for their benefit packages. The principal constraint is the low income of the contributing population (16, 17, 36, 46, Fig. 2). This is particularly true when most of the members of the community schemes are already below the poverty line.
Financial protection
Where household survey data have been analysed, researchers have consistently found community-based health financing to be effective in reaching low-income populations that would not otherwise have financial protection against the cost of illness (47). Improved financial protection was achieved through reducing scheme members' out-of-pocket spending, while increasing their use of health care services (42, 46, 48, 49). At the same time, some research suggested that the poorest of the poor and socially excluded groups were often not included in community-based initiatives for the financing of health care (46, 47, 50). Those studies that compared the level of financial protection of scheme members with that of non-members found that belonging to some form of prepayment scheme reduced the financial burden of seeking health care (44, 5052). Two studies indicated that community financing did not eliminate the need for broader coverage for catastrophic health care expenditures (53).
Combating social exclusion
Community-based health financing schemes also appear to extend coverage to a large number of rural and low-income populations that would otherwise be excluded from collective arrangements to pay for health care (41, 42, 44, 50). However, there have been reports that the poorest of the poor are often excluded from community financing arrangements. This is predominantly attributable to a lack of affordability.
On the basis of the 45 reports surveyed, we tried to assess what determinants contributed to successful and unsuccessful resource mobilization, financial protection, and social inclusion. Resource mobilization and financial protection appeared to be more successful where schemes had explicit mechanisms for dealing with adverse selection, accommodated the irregular and often non-cash revenue stream of their members, and had clear arrangements for the poorest people. Trained and competent management with strong involvement and ownership of the community contributed to the three performance measures that we reviewed. Schemes demonstrated greater sustainability where donor support and government funding were present.
Main findings of Asia and Africa regional reviews
The review of selected experiences in Asia and Africa (36, 37) provided additional support for the above conclusions, and demonstrate the diversity of community financing arrangements in these regions. Many of these arrangements appeared to improve financial protection against the cost of illness, to allow better access of poor households to essential health care, and to confer greater efficiency in the collection, pooling, management and use of scarce health care resources.
The existence of risk-sharing arrangements as well as trust in and local community control over the schemes appeared to increase enrolment in them. In particular, it was found that, although income was a key constraint to participation by the poorest of the poor, even these people were often willing and able to participate if their contributions were subsidized by public or donor funds and if there was access to good quality services. People were more likely to enrol if client households were directly involved in the design and management of the schemes. Furthermore, households were more likely to enrol if the premiums were based on prior assessments of local willingness to pay and if the benefits included easy access to a network of health providers.
Members of schemes sought broad coverage, including access to both basic health services for frequently encountered health problems and hospitalization for rarer conditions that were more expensive to treat. In the context of extreme resource constraints, this created a tension or trade-off between prepayment for basic services and the need for insurance coverage for rarer and more expensive and life-threatening events that might only occur once or twice in a lifetime. This observation is consistent with experience in other areas of insurance where willingness to pay for rare catastrophic events (life insurance) is often significantly reduced in comparison with readiness to pay for coverage of events that are more likely to happen with greater frequency (crop insurance). An area of market failure relating to voluntary community involvement in health care financing is thus highlighted. It should be confronted by government action, since it is precisely during hospital episodes that many of the poor become severely impoverished (Fig. 3).
The regional reviews also showed that a common feature of many reforms of the past two decades in low-income countries has been the introduction of copayments to influence utilization patterns and direct out-of-pocket user charges in order to obtain much-needed additional resources (54, 55). Most of the population does not benefit from formal insurance coverage, and government expenditure often fails to meet the basic health needs of the poor, let alone the whole population (56). These user charges add significantly to the financial hardship of poor households, which are often fully exposed to the financial risks associated with illness.
The review of selected experiences in Asia and Africa also suggested measures that governments could take to strengthen community financing. These included subsidizing the contributions made by the poor, providing technical assistance to improve capacity for scheme management, and the creation of links with formal health care networks. A critical factor was the matching of willingness and ability to pay with the expectation of benefits to be received at a later time. The regional reviews highlighted several areas of government action that appeared to have an adverse impact on the function of community financing schemes. Top-down interference with the design and management of the schemes appeared to have a particularly negative effect on their function and sustainability.
Main findings of micro-level household survey analysis
The aim of the micro-level household survey analysis (35) was to provide direct empirical evidence relating to the following questions.
What characteristics affect the decision of households to join community-based prepayment schemes?
Do community health financing schemes provide financial protection against the cost of illness for their members?
As standardized household surveys did not allow us to pursue these matters, five small-scale, non-standardized household surveys were selected for analysis. Two data sets were obtained for India, and one was obtained for each of Rwanda, Senegal, and Thailand.
Determinants of social inclusion in community financing
The main findings of the study suggested that community financing can be inclusive of the poor, even in the most economically deprived context: in India and Rwanda the poor were just as likely to be part of a prepayment scheme as the non-poor. On the other hand, this cannot be generalized to all community financing schemes. In Senegal and Thailand, for example, household income was a significant determinant of membership of a prepayment scheme. This suggested that community financing structures did not automatically remove financial barriers to risk protection in the sample of schemes that we analysed. It was concluded that the design characteristics of the schemes might significantly affect the achievement of good targeting under community schemes, just as they mattered for large-scale public expenditure programmes.
Determinants of financial protection in community financing
In three of the surveys, members of community financing schemes reported higher use of health care and at the same time lower out-of-pocket expenditures. This confirmed the original hypothesis that prepayment and the pooling of risk reduced financial barriers to health care. Furthermore, the analysis indicated that, even when individuals were members of a community financing scheme, being poor and lacking the ability to pay additional out-of-pocket charges remained a significant barrier to access.
Main findings of macro-level cross-country analysis
Most routine statistical sources at national level do not include data on the share of overall financing that is channelled through either community-based or private health insurance schemes (57). The macro-level analysis therefore focused on the degree of collective risk-sharing provided at low income levels through different combinations of general tax revenues and social insurance. The objective was to examine the degree to which risk-sharing had a beneficial impact on the five indicators of health systems performance described in The world health report 2000 (3).
The results of the macro-level cross-country analysis gave empirical support to the hypothesis that broad risk-sharing in health financing had a significant impact on the level and distribution of health, financial fairness and responsiveness indicators. The results even suggested that risk-sharing corrected for, and possibly outweighed, the negative effect of overall income inequality. This would mean that financial protection against the cost of illness might be a more effective strategy for poverty alleviation in some settings than direct income support.
Conclusions and recommendations
Most community financing schemes have evolved in settings of severe economic constraint, political instability and unsatisfactory governance. Usually, government taxation capacity is weak, formal mechanisms of social protection for vulnerable populations are absent, and government oversight of the informal health sector is lacking. In such circumstances, community involvement provides a first step towards improved financial protection against the cost of illness and improved access to priority health services.
Governments can contribute to the effectiveness and sustainability of community health financing schemes for rural, informal sector and poor populations through key policies involving the following: increased and well-targeted subsidies boosting the health insurance contributions of low- income populations; insurance for protection against fluctuations in expenditure; reinsurance to enlarge the effective size of small risk pools and cover catastrophic events; prevention and case management techniques to limit expenditure fluctuations; technical support to strengthen the management capacity of local schemes; and the establishment and strengthening of links with formal financing and provider networks.
Conflicts of interest: none declared.
Résumé
Efficacité du financement communautaire de la santé pour faire face au coût de la maladie
L'un des plus grands défis auxquels se trouve confrontée la communauté internationale pour le développement est de savoir comment financer et assurer les soins nécessaires à plus de 1,3 milliard de travailleurs démunis des zones rurales et du secteur informel dans les pays à revenu faible et moyen. Le présent article récapitule les principaux résultats d'une vaste étude de la littérature traitant des mécanismes financiers communautaires, ainsi qu'un certain nombre d'expériences réalisées dans les régions de l'Afrique et de l'Asie. Pour la plupart, les systèmes de financement communautaire ont été élaborés sur fond de sérieuses difficultés économiques, d'instabilité politique et de mauvaise gestion des affaires publiques. Une microanalyse des données relatives aux ménages indique que le financement par la collectivité améliore l'accès des travailleurs des zones rurales et du secteur informel aux soins dont ils ont besoin, leur assurant en quelque sorte une protection financière face au coût de la maladie. Une macroanalyse de l'ensemble des pays vient renforcer de manière empirique l'hypothèse selon laquelle le partage des risques en matière de financement de la santé a d'importantes répercussions tant sur le niveau que sur la distribution des indicateurs de la santé, de l'équité du financement et de la capacité de réactivité.
Les recherches faites dans le cadre du présent article font ressortir cinq grandes options que les gouvernements peuvent choisir pour améliorer l'efficacité et la viabilité des systèmes de financement existant au niveau communautaire, à savoir : a) subventions accrues et bien ciblées pour garantir le paiement des primes des populations à faible revenu ; b) assurance contre les fluctuations des dépenses et réassurance pour augmenter la taille réelle des petites caisses d'assurance de groupe ; c) techniques efficaces de prévention et de prise en charge des cas pour limiter les fluctuations des dépenses ; d) appui technique pour renforcer la capacité de gestion des caisses locales ; et e) création et renforcement des liens avec les réseaux officiels de financement et de prestataires.
Resumen
Eficacia del financiamiento comunitario de la salud para hacer frente al costo de las enfermedades
Uno de los grandes retos que afronta la comunidad internacional para el desarrollo consiste en determinar la manera de financiar y prestar la atención sanitaria que necesitan los más de 1300 millones de pobres rurales y trabajadores del sector no estructurado que hay en los países de ingresos bajos y medios. En este artículo se presentan los principales resultados de un extenso estudio de la literatura relativa a los arreglos de financiamiento comunitario, así como determinadas experiencias de las regiones de Asia y África. La mayoría de los sistemas de financiamiento comunitario se han desarrollado en un contexto de graves limitaciones económicas, inestabilidad política y falta de una buena gobernanza. El microanálisis de los datos de hogares indica que el financiamiento comunitario mejora el acceso de los trabajadores rurales y del sector no estructurado a la atención sanitaria que necesitan y les garantiza cierta protección financiera frente a los gastos causados por las enfermedades. El macroanálisis por países proporciona apoyo empírico a la hipótesis de que la participación en el riesgo en materia de financiamiento sanitario tiene un efecto importante en cuanto atañe tanto al nivel como a la distribución de los indicadores de salud, equidad financiera y capacidad de respuesta.
La investigación de fondo realizada para este artículo apunta a cinco políticas clave de las que disponen los gobiernos para mejorar la eficacia y sostenibilidad de los planes de financiamiento comunitario existentes. Se trata de las siguientes: (a) subvenciones más cuantiosas y bien focalizadas para pagar las primas de las poblaciones de bajos ingresos; (b) seguros contra las fluctuaciones de los gastos, y reaseguros para ampliar el tamaño eficaz de los sistemas pequeños de mancomunación del riesgo; (c) técnicas eficaces de prevención y gestión de casos para limitar las fluctuaciones de gastos; (d) apoyo técnico para reforzar la capacidad de gestión de los planes locales, y (e) creación, y refuerzo, de vínculos con las redes formales de financiamiento y de proveedores.
References
1. World Bank. Sector strategy for HNP. Washington (DC): World Bank; 1997.
2. World Bank. World development report 1993: investing in health. New York: Oxford University Press; 1993.
3. The world health report 2000. Health systems: measuring performance. Geneva: World Health Organization; 2000.
4. Jha P, Mills A. Interventions, constraints and costs in improving health outcomes of the poor. (Working Group 5, background report to the Commission on Macroeconomics and Health, 2001).
5. Preker AS, Langenbrunner J, Suzuki E. The global expenditure gap in securing financial protection and access to health care for the poor. (Working Group 3, background report to the Commission on Macroeconomics and Health).
6. Preker AS, Langenbrunner J, Jakab M. Rich-poor differences in health care financing. In: Dror D, Preker AS, editors. Social reinsurance: a new approach to sustain community health financing. Washington (DC): World Bank/ILO; (forthcoming).
7. Preker AS, Carrin G, Dror D, Jakab M, Hsiao W, Arhin-Tenkorang D. Health care financing for rural and low-income populations: the role of communities in resource mobilization and risk sharing. (Background report to Commission on Macroeconomics and Health, 2001).
8. Schieber G, Maeda A. A curmudgeon's guide to health care financing in developing countries. In: Schieber G, editor. Innovations in health care financing. Washington (DC): World Bank; 1997 Proceedings of a World Bank Conference, 10-11 March 1997.
9. Van Ginneken W. Social security for the informal sector: new challenges for the developing countries. International Social Security Review 1999; 52(1):49-69.
10. Midgely J, Tracey MB. Challenges to social security: an international exploration. Westport (CT): Auburn House; 1996.
11. World Bank. World development report 1995. Workers in an integrating world. Washington (DC): World Bank; 1995.
12. Guhan S. Social security options for developing countries. International Labour Review 1994;33(1):35-53.
13. Wagstaff AN, Watanabe N, van Doorslaer E. Impoverishment, insurance, and health care payments. Washington (DC): World Bank; 2001 (discussion paper).
14. Gwatkin D. Poverty and inequalities in health within developing countries: filling the information gap. In: Leon D, Walt G, editors. Poverty, inequality, and health: an international perspective. Oxford: Oxford University Press; 2001. p. 217-46.
15. Peters D, Yazbeck A, Ramana GNV, Sharma R. India raising the sights: better health systems for India's poor. Washington (DC): World Bank; 2001.
16. Bennett S, Creese A, Monasch R. Health insurance schemes for people outside formal sector employment. Geneva: World Health Organization; 1998. ARA Paper No. 16.
17. Atim C. Contribution of mutual health to financing, delivery, and access to health care. Synthesis of research in nine West and Central African countries. Bethesda (MD): Abt Associates; 1998. Partnerships for Health Reform Project, Technical Report No. 18.
18. Musau S. Community-based health insurance: experiences and lessons learned from East and Southern Africa. Bethesda (MD): Abt Associates; 1999. Partnerships for Health Reform Project, Technical Report No. 34.
19. Ziemek S, Jütting J. Mutual insurance schemes and social protection. Geneva: International Labour Organization; 2000. STEP Research Group on Civil Society and Social Economy.
20. Jakab M, Krishnan C. Community involvement in health care: a survey of the literature on the impact, strengths and weaknesses. (Working Group 3, background report to Commission on Macroeconomics and Health, 2001.
21. Dror D, Preker AS, Jakab M. Role of communities in combating social exclusion. In: Dror D, Preker AS, editors. Social reinsurance: a new approach to sustain community health financing. Washington (DC): World Bank/ILO; (forthcoming).
22. Asian Development Bank. Finance for the poor: microfinance development strategy. Manila: Asian Development Bank; 2000.
23. Brown W, Churchill C. Insurance provision in low-income communities. Part II. Initial lessons from micro-insurance experiments for the poor. Micro- enterprise best practices. Bethesda (MD): Development Alternatives Inc; 2000.
24. Zeller M, Sharma M. Many borrow, more save, and all insure: implications for food and micro-finance policy. Food Policy 2000;25(2):143-67.
25. Otero M, Rhyne E, editors. The new world of microenterprise finance: building healthy financial institutions for the poor. West Hartford (CT): Kumarian Press; 1994.
26. Dror D, Jacquier C. Micro-insurance: extending health insurance to the excluded. International Social Security Review 1999;52(1):71-97.
27. Dror D. Reinsurance of health insurance for the informal sector. Bulletin of the World Health Organization 2001;79(7):672-8.
28. Bator F. The anatomy of market failure. Quarterly Journal of Economics 1958;72(3):351-79
29. Arrow KW. Uncertainty and the welfare economics of medical care. American Economic Review 1963;53(5):940-73.
30. Atkinson AB, Stiglitz JE. Lectures on public economics. Maidenhead: McGraw-Hill; 1980.
31. Evans RG. Strained mercy. Toronto: Butterworth; 1984.
32. Musgrave RA, Musgrave PB. Public finance in theory and practice. New York: McGraw-Hill; 1984.
33. Barer LM, Getzen TE, Stoddart GL, editors. Health, health care and health economics: perspectives on distribution. Chichester: John Wiley and Sons; 1998.
34. Van Doorslaer E, Wagstaff A, Rutten F, editors. Equity in the finance and delivery of health care: an international perspective. Oxford: Oxford Medical Publications; 1993.
35. Jakab M, Preker A, Krishnan C, Schneider P, Diop F, Jütting J, et al. Social inclusion and financial protection through community financing: initial results from five household surveys. (Working Group 3, background report to Commission on Macroeconomics and Health, 2001).
36. Hsiao WC. Unmet health needs of two billion: is community financing a solution? (Working Group 3, background report to Commission on Macroeconomics and Health, 2001).
37. Arhin-Tenkorang DC. Health insurance for the informal sector in Africa: design features, risk protection and resource mobilization. (Working Group 3, background report to Commission on Macroeconomics and Health, 2001).
38. Carrin G, Zeramdini R. The impact of the degree of risk-sharing in health financing on health system attainment. (Working Group 3, background report to Commission on Macroeconomics and Health, 2001).
39. Navarro VA. Critique of the ideological and political position of the Brandt Report and the Alma-Ata declaration. International Journal of Health Services 1984;2(14):159-72.
40. Foster G. Community development and primary health care: their conceptual similarities. Medical Anthropology 1982;6:183-95.
41. McPake B, Hanson K, Mills A. Community financing of health care in Africa: an evaluation of the Bamako Initiative. Social Science and Medicine 1993;3(11):1383-95.
42. Criel B, Van der Stuyft P, Van Lerbergher W. The Bwamanda hospital insurance scheme: effective for whom? A study of its impact on hospitalisation and utilisation patterns. Social Science and Medicine 1999;48(7):879-911.
43. Dave P. Community and self-financing in voluntary health programmes in India. Health Policy and Planning 1991;6(1):20-31.
44. Diop F, Yazbeck A, Bitran R. The impact of alternative cost recovery schemes on access and equity in Niger. Health Policy and Planning 1995;10(3):223- 40.
45. Soucat A, Gandaho T, Levy-Bruhl D, de Bethune X, Alihonou E, Ortiz C, et al. Health seeking behavior and household expenditures in Benin and Guinea: the equity implications of the Bamako Initiative. International Journal of Health Planning and Management 1997;12(Suppl 1):137-63.
46. Jütting J. Do mutual health insurance schemes improve the access to health care? Preliminary results from a household survey in rural Senegal. International Conference on Health Systems Financing in Low-Income African and Asian Countries CERDI, Paris; 2000.
47. Litvack JI, Bodart CI. User fees plus quality equals improved access to health care: results of a field experiment in Cameroon. Social Science and Medicine 1992;37(3):369-83.
48. Desmet A, Chowdhury AQ, Islam KM. The potential for social mobilization in Bangladesh: the organization and functioning of two health insurance schemes. Social Science and Medicine 1999;48(7):925-38.
49. Supakankunti S. Future prospects of voluntary health insurance in Thailand. Cambridge (MA): Harvard University; 1997. Takemi Research Paper No. 13. Takemi Program in International Health. Harvard School of Public Health.
50. Arhin-Tenkorang DC. The health card insurance scheme in Burundi: a social asset or a non-viable venture? Social Science and Medicine 1994;39(6):861-70.
51. DeRoeck D, Knowles J, Wittenberg,T, Raney L, Cordova P. Rural health services at Seguridad Social Campesino facilities: analyses of facility and household surveys. Bethesda (MD): Abt Associates Inc., Health Financing and Sustainability Project; 1996. Technical Report No. 13.
52. Gumber A, Kulkarni V. Health insurance for the informal sector: case study of Gujarat. Economic and Political Weekly 30 September 2000:3607-13.
53. Pradhan M, Prescott N. Social risk management for medical care in Indonesia. International Conference on Health Systems Financing in Low- Income African and Asian Countries, CERDI, Paris; 2000.
54. Arhin-Tenkorang DC. Mobilizing resources for health: the case for user fees re-visited. (Working Group 3, background report to Commission on Macroeconomics and Health, 2001).
55. Vogel RJ. Health insurance in sub-Saharan Africa. Washington (DC): World Bank; 1990. African Technical Department, Working Paper Series. p. 476.
56. Abel-Smith B, Rawal P. Employer's willingness to pay: the case for compulsory health insurance in Tanzania. Health Policy and Planning 1994;9(4):409-18.
57. Carrin G, Desmet M, Basaza R. Social health insurance development in low-income developing countries: new roles for government and non-profit health insurance organisations. In: Building social security: the challenge for privatization. Geneva: International Social Security Association; 2001.
* Based on: Preker AS, Carrin G, Dror D, Jakab M, Hsiao W, Arhin-Tenkorang D. Health care financing for rural and low-income populations: the role of communities in resource mobilization and risk sharing. (A synthesis background report to Commission on Macroeconomics and Health. Available at: URL: http:// www.cmhealth.org/wg3.htm).
1 Chief Economist for Health Nutrition and Population, The World Bank, 1818 H Street, Mail Stop G7-702, NW, Washington DC, 20433, USA (email: apreker@worldbank.org). Correspondence should be addressed to this author.
2 Senior Economist, Designing Policy Options: Financing, Resource Allocation, Regulation and Legislation, World Health Organization, Geneva, Switzerland.
3 Health Specialist, International Labour Organization, Geneva, Switzerland.
4 PhD Candidate, School of Public Health, Harvard University, Boston, MA, USA.
5 Professor, School of Public Health, Harvard University, Boston, MA, USA.
6 Researcher, Center for International Development, Harvard University, Boston, MA, USA.
Ref . No. 01-1570