Expensive medicines: ensuring objective appraisal and equitable access

Suzanne R Hill Lisa Bero Geoff McColl Elizabeth Roughead About the authors

In response to requests for the funding of new drugs, reimbursement agencies are re-evaluating some of the methods used in assessing these products. Many trials submitted for the regulatory review of new drugs do not provide adequate data for subsidy decisions. We argue that all involved in bringing medicines to market need to be explicit about the additional information required, decide how these data should be collected and assessed and the methods that should be used to set a fair price for a new drug.

In Australia, a formal appraisal of the cost–effectiveness and budget impact of a new medicine precedes any subsidy decision at national level.1Clement FM, Harris A, Li JJ, Yong K, Lee KM, Manns BJ. Using effectiveness and cost-effectiveness to make drug coverage decisions: a comparison of Britain, Australia, and Canada. JAMA. 2009;302(13):1437–43.
https://doi.org/10.1001/jama.2009.1409...
If a new product is subsidized, the government pays an agreed price to the manufacturer, sometimes with requirements for financial contracts to manage expenditure.2Vitry A, Roughead E. Managed entry agreements for pharmaceuticals in Australia. Health Policy. 2014;117(3):345–52.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.healthpol.2014...

Increasingly, patients are asking for early access to new drugs, particularly for treating cancer. In consequence, strategies to subsidize drugs for use under conditions of coverage with evidence development or managed entry are being proposed. A new drug might be approved even if there is no evidence to show that it satisfies the standards typically applied in health technology assessments. However, this approval is often contingent upon additional requirements for subsequent randomized trials or the collection of data on the drug’s effectiveness and safety in practice. There is no consensus on the best methods for identifying drugs appropriate for managed entry schemes, for collecting post-approval data or for the use of such data to modify decisions about coverage.

In Australia, as in many other countries, several questions need to be answered. Can stakeholders produce a workable framework for managed entry schemes? What can be done to reduce variation in the inputs used for cost–effectiveness models? How can drug or disease registries contribute useful information to inform reimbursement decisions? How should registry data be evaluated? What can be done to make registry data more representative of the population and what types of post-progression data should be included in trials of targeted cancer therapies?

Regulatory agencies, insurers and clinicians also need to be able to determine if a new drug represents good value for money and what to do if an effective drug appears too highly priced for the benefit that it offers. The prices of several recently-introduced drugs – for example aflibercept, ivacaftor and sofosbuvir – have been questioned.3Bach PB, Saltz LB, Wittes RE. In cancer care, cost matters. New York Times. 2012 Oct 14.

Cohen D, Raftery J. Paying twice: questions over high cost of cystic fibrosis drug developed with charitable funding. BMJ. 2014;348:g1445.
https://doi.org/10.1136/bmj.g1445...
-5Sanger-Katz M. $1,000 hepatitis pill shows why fixing health costs is so hard. New York Times. 2014 Aug 2.

The way in which drug prices change over time has generally been a function of the market. Typically, a new drug is launched under patent and can command a good price until the patent expires and competition and/or generic products emerge. Exceptionally, public pressure and legal challenges decreased the price of several antiretroviral drugs in countries with high burdens of human immunodeficiency virus before patent expiry.6Yamey G. Drug companies cut HIV drug prices in the developing world. BMJ. 2000;320(7246):1357.
https://doi.org/10.1136/bmj.320.7246.135...
Other strategies, such as compulsory licensing, have had limited success.7Mohara A, Yamabhai I, Chaisiri K, Tantivess S, Teerawattananon Y. Impact of the introduction of government use licenses on the drug expenditure on seven medicines in Thailand. Value Health. 2012;15(1) Suppl:S95–9.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jval.2011.11.0...
Tiered pricing has also been proposed but defining each tier and an appropriate price for each has proved challenging.8Danzon P, Towse A, Mestre-Ferrandiz J. Value-based differential pricing: efficient prices for drugs in a global context. Health Econ. 2013.
https://doi.org/10.1002/hec.3021...
The recent approval of high-priced medicines for many conditions has prompted a new round of discussions9Fojo T, Mailankody S, Lo A. Unintended consequences of expensive cancer therapeutics-the pursuit of marginal indications and a me-too mentality that stifles innovation and creativity: the John Conley Lecture. JAMA Otolaryngol Head Neck Surg. 2014.
https://doi.org/10.1001/jamaoto.2014.157...
and calls for radical changes to the current commercial model for drug development.1010 Jayadev A, Stiglitz J. Two ideas to increase innovation and reduce pharmaceutical costs and prices. Health Aff (Millwood). 2009;28(1):w165–8.
https://doi.org/10.1377/hlthaff.28.1.w16...

We consider that it is time for a global forum to discuss objectivity and equity in access to high-priced drugs. Such a forum should extend beyond the usual networks of payers and authorities on health technology assessment. It needs to define the methods needed to manage the early entry of promising products – i.e. how to evaluate the data that are available for early market entry, determine an appropriate initial price, optimize the collection of data from clinical practice, enable independent trials and manage the exit of products that, in practice, are found to be insufficiently effective. The forum should promote the development of a method for pricing new drugs. Such a method needs to reconcile the need for fair pricing, with the difficulties of obtaining accurate information on research, development and manufacturing costs. The forum should include representatives of patient and consumer groups, so that the right questions are asked, appropriate research priorities are set and outcomes are communicated.

In managing access to new drugs, simply continuing to react country-by-country and disease-by-disease is not sustainable. We need to be more forward-thinking and take some of the pressure off small purchasers and countries that are currently trying to make equitable decisions in isolation. We need to solve the fundamental problem of how to balance objectivity of appraisal and equity in access to new products; ensuring that medical advances are affordable, working with a viable pharmaceutical industry that responds to public health needs.

Acknowledgements

SRH is the chair of the Australian Pharmaceutical Benefits Advisory Committee (PBAC). GM is a member of the PBAC and chair of the Drug Utilisation Sub-Committee (DUSC) of PBAC. ER is a member of DUSC.

References

  • 1
    Clement FM, Harris A, Li JJ, Yong K, Lee KM, Manns BJ. Using effectiveness and cost-effectiveness to make drug coverage decisions: a comparison of Britain, Australia, and Canada. JAMA. 2009;302(13):1437–43.
    » https://doi.org/10.1001/jama.2009.1409
  • 2
    Vitry A, Roughead E. Managed entry agreements for pharmaceuticals in Australia. Health Policy. 2014;117(3):345–52.
    » https://doi.org/10.1016/j.healthpol.2014.05.005
  • 3
    Bach PB, Saltz LB, Wittes RE. In cancer care, cost matters. New York Times. 2012 Oct 14.
  • 4
    Cohen D, Raftery J. Paying twice: questions over high cost of cystic fibrosis drug developed with charitable funding. BMJ. 2014;348:g1445.
    » https://doi.org/10.1136/bmj.g1445
  • 5
    Sanger-Katz M. $1,000 hepatitis pill shows why fixing health costs is so hard. New York Times. 2014 Aug 2.
  • 6
    Yamey G. Drug companies cut HIV drug prices in the developing world. BMJ. 2000;320(7246):1357.
    » https://doi.org/10.1136/bmj.320.7246.1357
  • 7
    Mohara A, Yamabhai I, Chaisiri K, Tantivess S, Teerawattananon Y. Impact of the introduction of government use licenses on the drug expenditure on seven medicines in Thailand. Value Health. 2012;15(1) Suppl:S95–9.
    » https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jval.2011.11.016
  • 8
    Danzon P, Towse A, Mestre-Ferrandiz J. Value-based differential pricing: efficient prices for drugs in a global context. Health Econ. 2013.
    » https://doi.org/10.1002/hec.3021
  • 9
    Fojo T, Mailankody S, Lo A. Unintended consequences of expensive cancer therapeutics-the pursuit of marginal indications and a me-too mentality that stifles innovation and creativity: the John Conley Lecture. JAMA Otolaryngol Head Neck Surg. 2014.
    » https://doi.org/10.1001/jamaoto.2014.1570
  • 10
    Jayadev A, Stiglitz J. Two ideas to increase innovation and reduce pharmaceutical costs and prices. Health Aff (Millwood). 2009;28(1):w165–8.
    » https://doi.org/10.1377/hlthaff.28.1.w165

Publication Dates

    Creative Common -
    This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution IGO License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/3.0/igo/legalcode), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited. In any reproduction of this article there should not be any suggestion that WHO or this article endorse any specific organization or products. The use of the WHO logo is not permitted. This notice should be preserved along with the article's original URL.
    World Health Organization Genebra - Genebra - Switzerland
    E-mail: bulletin@who.int