Brazilian healthcare in the context of austerity: private sector dominant, government sector failing

Nilson do Rosário Costa About the author

Abstract

This paper presents the arguments in favor of government intervention in financing and regulation of health in Brazil. It describes the organizational arrangement of the Brazilian health system, for the purpose of reflection on the austerity agenda proposed for the country. Based on the literature in health economics, it discusses the hypothesis that the health sector in Brazil functions under the dominance of the private sector. The categories employed for analysis are those of the national health spending figures. An international comparison of indicators of health expenses shows that Brazilian public spending is a low proportion of total spending on Brazilian health. Expenditure on individuals’ health by out-of-pocket payments is high, and this works against equitability. The private health services sector plays a crucial role in provision, and financing. Contrary to the belief put forward by the austerity agenda, public expenditure cannot be constrained because the government has failed in adequate provision of services to the poor. This paper argues that, since the Constitution did not veto activity by the private sector segment of the market, those interests that have the greatest capacity to vocalize have been successful in imposing their preferences in the configuration of the sector.

Austerity; Health insurance; Out-of-pocket payments; Health plans; Public expenditure

Introduction

Vocalization of concepts of fiscal adjustment and control of public expenditure has grown to an extraordinary degree in the political-crisis context that has affected Brazilian democracy this year11. Ames B. Os entraves da democracia no Brasil: uma crise antevista? Folha de S. Paulo 2016 maio 13.. The formulators of the austerity agenda have argued for the financing of a basic health package, bringing back into consideration an agenda from the 1990s of unrestricted focus on government intervention in the social area.

Lisboa22. Lisboa M. Entrevista. Valor Econômico 2016 jun 23; p. 8., for example, argues for austerity in the following terms: “I would separate whatever is basic education, whatever is basic health care, whatever is transfer of income to the poorest 10%. These funds should be preserved. They can even grow by more than inflation – not by a lot, but by a little. But all the rest need to be reviewed”.

Defense of containment of expenditures on the scale imagined by this author causes enormous discomfort, because it is a consensus among analysts of public policies that in contemporary society the social compact is unfeasible without active governmental participation in financing and coordination of the provision of public goods. Further, due to the singular nature of the health sector, the scope and scale of regulatory intervention by the government should go much further than the provision of basic care.

One can have recourse to Arrow33. Arrow KJ. Uncertainty and the Welfare Economics of Medical Care. American Economic Review 1963; 53(5):941-973. to show that, in contrast to the demand for common goods, such as health and clothing or other private assets, the demand for health services is unpredictable. Indeed, since illness is so very unpredictable, individual demand for medical services, with the exception of their preventive aspects, tends to largely reflect the uncertainties inherent in the functioning of unregulated markets. Also, demand for healthcare may be directly associated with the risk of loss of capacity to work, and indeed in extreme cases loss of life itself, and is not something that can be postponed33. Arrow KJ. Uncertainty and the Welfare Economics of Medical Care. American Economic Review 1963; 53(5):941-973..

The supply of healthcare also has significant differences in relation to traditional products, in two aspects: the first is the high dependence of the patient on professional intervention, especially medical care. Arrow believes that it is necessary to highlight that medical activity, which is supposedly oriented by the concern with the wellbeing of the patient and of the collective, can be influenced by the quest for income, with important effects on the effectiveness of the treatment. Secondly, the access to diagnostic and input services (laboratory tests, imaging, consumption of medication) is determined by a professional decision, in such a way that the patient does not have control over important components of the treatment process33. Arrow KJ. Uncertainty and the Welfare Economics of Medical Care. American Economic Review 1963; 53(5):941-973..

Healthcare is, thus, a good which differs substantially from other essential services. In most situations, there is a low probability that an individual will have a serious or chronic illness during the course of their life. But if they do, it is highly unlikely that they will be in a position to finance the treatment with their own funds or those of family members44. Hsiao W. Comparing Health Care Systems: What Nations Can Learn from One Another. Journal of Health Politics, Policy and Law 1992; 17(4):613-636..

The cost of contemporary medicine (diagnoses, treatments, surgery and hospitalization) is in no way financeable from the pocket of the majority of individuals. Studies in the 1990s already showed that in countries of average income such as Brazil, between 20% and 30% of families had to take a loan or sell assets to pay medical expenses55. Hsiao W, Heller PS. What Should Macroeconomists Know about Health Care Policy? IMF Working Papers 2013.. A family’s decision to go into debt for health treatment produces a catastrophic pattern in the family’s spending66. Xu K, Evans DB, Kawabata K, Zeramdini R, Klavus J, Murray CJ. Household catastrophic health expenditure: a multicountry analysis. Lancet 2003; 362(9378):111-117..

Thus, it is not possible to individually plan the future consumption of healthcare that is of high cost, due to the devastating consequences for families and individuals77. Castro JD. Regulação em saúde: análise de conceitos fundamentais. Sociologias 2002; 1(7):122-135.. This is why, as Hsiao55. Hsiao W, Heller PS. What Should Macroeconomists Know about Health Care Policy? IMF Working Papers 2013. has warned, it is extremely worrying that targets for public spending and fiscal burden formulated by political leaders and economists do not explain and make clear the regressive effects on availability of services and inputs and, in the last analysis, on the financial and health conditions of the population.

The existence of a market in health services that is not regulated, or is incompletely regulated by the government, favors: (i) development of the private insurance sector; and (2) transfer of the burden of financing of expenses on health to out-of-pocket expenditure by families.

The problems associated with deregulation of healthcare are thus in no way trivial. Private healthcare plan companies and insurance companies are oriented to achieving profitability. For this reason, the cost of the insurance premium has to be greater than the actual cost of possible healthcare that the insured person might come to need. However, the health plans and the insurance companies do not know the risks for each individual and calculate the value of the premium based on an average risk77. Castro JD. Regulação em saúde: análise de conceitos fundamentais. Sociologias 2002; 1(7):122-135..

Individuals who buy a private health insurance tend to know more about their health conditions and, when they perceive that their risk is lower than the average of people who are insured, they opt not to participate in the insurance. When the insured people with lower risk stop participating, it increases the average risk of the group that continues to be interested and, consequently, the final premium price. This situation repeats itself indefinitely for those who remain, because the risks will never be the same for all77. Castro JD. Regulação em saúde: análise de conceitos fundamentais. Sociologias 2002; 1(7):122-135..

As a way of getting around the effects of this process, companies and health plans create insurances that evaluate the risk of each individual based on personal and family history. The direct result of the strategy of risk selection is increased in the value of the premium for the groups of highest risk (chronic sufferers, the elderly) who, normally, do not have the ability to pay the cost of insurance and will remain without cover77. Castro JD. Regulação em saúde: análise de conceitos fundamentais. Sociologias 2002; 1(7):122-135., demanding government care.

The out-of-pocket expenditure mode of paying for healthcare is associated with the liberal scheme of organization of financing – the starting point of every experience of developing a provision for healthcare in any country. The liberal provision rests, on the supply side, on ample autonomy of health professionals and of companies, who hold the monopoly of competence in provision of the services. On the demand side, the liberal model is sustained by the format of acquisition of health services by individuals or families through out-of-pocket expenditure. Expenditure by out-of-pocket expenditure results in the catastrophic expenditure patterns referred to above, and leads to the impoverishment of families66. Xu K, Evans DB, Kawabata K, Zeramdini R, Klavus J, Murray CJ. Household catastrophic health expenditure: a multicountry analysis. Lancet 2003; 362(9378):111-117..

Faced with the limitations of market-based options, the democratic societies adopted public financing for health services as a way of avoiding the bankruptcy of individuals and families in response to the risk of serious, chronic or incapacitating illness. Esping-Andersen88. Esping-Anderser G. As Três Economias Políticas do Welfare State. Lua Nova 1991; 1(24):85-115. identifies, in this experience, the process of de-mercantilization, indicating that countries choose the construction of ‘regimes’ of social protection against families’ dependence on the dynamics of the market in areas that are considered to be critical.

The construction of public welfare systems after the Second World War, and the crises and reforms of the 1990s, produced a vast comparative bibliography on the national health systems in the context of the protection regimes99. Moran M. Understanding the welfare state: the case of health care British Journal of Politics and International Relations 2000; 2(2):135-160.. The literature identifies two ideal types of government financing regime. The first is based on the idea of universal right, in which societies delegate to the instances of government the decision to allocate the majority of the funds in the sector. The second is associated with the scheme of public health insurance1010. Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD). Proposal for a Taxonomy of Health Insurance. OECD Study on Private Health Insurance, OECD Health Project. June 2004. [acessado 2013 dez 23]. Disponível em: http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/24/52/31916207.pdf
http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/24/52/31916...
.

In the first model, governmental intervention in the financing is the variable that determines the level of de-mercantilization in the field of health. The dominance of government expenses, financed by taxes and contributions, indicates the adoption of institutional market coordination mechanisms, reducing the options of individuals, professionals and companies for achieving improved conditions of access1111. Savedoff WD, de Ferranti D, Smith AL, Fan V. Political and economic aspects of the transition to universal health coverage. Lancet 2012; 380(9845):924-932..

The countries with regimes of instituted social protection finance the health services using the coordination of the government1111. Savedoff WD, de Ferranti D, Smith AL, Fan V. Political and economic aspects of the transition to universal health coverage. Lancet 2012; 380(9845):924-932.. Paradoxically, this is the model adopted in the central economies where the access to health services is not limited to a basic basket of health services, and restricted to preventive interventions of low complexity.

The second social protection regime based on health insurance also has wide-ranging governmental intervention, and is adopted in the rich continental countries of Europe. This arrangement is based on the corporate compact1212. Schmitter PC. Still the Century of Corporatism? The Review of Politics 1974; 36(1):85-131, where workers and government employees are protected by the national government from liberal practices in healthcare through the institutions of social security/insurance. The source of funds is the financial contribution by employers, employees and governments to parastatal entities that manage social security.

When social security was put in place in the medium-income countries, the access to healthcare took place in a highly stratified form due to the informality of the labor market. In these countries, employees with formal employment have the exclusivity in the use of the health services provided by the social security, which is not the case in the central economies with corporate systems. The population of the informal sector of the medium-income countries accesses healthcare through out-of-pocket expenditure or through basic and focal health programs. The example of Mexico is a paradigm in this regard1313. Costa NR. Estudo de Caso: México. In: Biasoto G, Silva PLB, Dain S, organizadores. Regulação do Setor Saúde nas Américas: As Relações Entre o Público e o Privado. Brasília: Organização Panamericana de Saúde, Agência Nacional de Saúde Suplementar; 2006. p. 375-392..

In Brazil, two and a half decades have gone by since a universal health access system was approved by the federal constitution in 19881414. Weyland K. Social Movements and the State: The Politics of Health Reform in Brazil. World Development 1995; 23(10):1699-1712.. Over the course of the democratic transition of the 1980s, the members of the Constitutional Assembly accepted the model based on the predominance of public financing and direct provision by healthcare by the government1515. Costa NR. Comunidade epistêmica e a formação da reforma sanitária no Brasil. Physis 2014; 24(3):809-829..

The chapter of the 1988 Federal Constitution dealing with health, and the enabling laws and Ministerial Orders, aim to achieve integration of the actions taken by public health and individual medical assistance in a single system with universal and equitable access – the Single Health System (Sistema Único de Saúde, or SUS)1616. Faveret Filho P, Oliveira PJ. A universalização excludente: reflexões sobre as tendências do sistema de saúde. Planejamento e Políticas Públicas 1990; 3(1):139-162..

The 1988 Constitution innovated in that it created the Social Security Budget to finance the activities of social security, social assistance and health1717. Brasil. Constituição da República Federativa do Brasil de 1988. Diário Oficial da União 1988; 5 out.. In the light of these changes, Draibe1818. Draibe SM. Há Tendências e Tendências: Com que Estado de Bem Estar Social Haveremos de Conviver? Cadernos de Pesquisa NEPP Unicamp 1989; 1(10):1-89. suggests that the 1988 Constitution made a break with the social protection system built over the course of the Republican regime, due to the emphasis given to the dimension of ‘security’ in social policies as a whole. The social security dimension, he said, was defined by the condition of financing through taxes and contributions and through the criterion of universal access to the benefits.

Contemporary studies on the development of the Brazilian health system describe it, however, as a system that is fragmented and under the predominance of the private sector1919. Paim J, Travassos C, Almeida C, Bahia L, Macinko J. The Brazilian health system: history, advances, and challenges. Lancet 2011; 1(377):1778 -1797.,2020. Costa NR, Vaitsman J. Universalization and Privatization: How Policy Analysis Can Help Understand the Development of Brazil’s Health System. Journal of Comparative Policy Analysis: Research and Practice 2014; 16(5):441-456.. The present format of the Brazilian health sector does not correspond to the configurations delineated by the 1988 Constitution, due to the limitation of government activity and the role of the private sector in the financing and provision of services.

The 1988 Constitution did not constrain the action of the market in the health sector with the intensity necessary for institutionalization of a universal access model for health services. On the contrary, it ratified the composition between the government and the market, developed in the country since the 1970s, by declaring that ‘private initiative is free to operate in healthcare’. The members of the constitutional assembly did not at the time have sufficient information to identify the structural dynamic of the market in healthcare in Brazil, and attributed to the private sector only functions that were ‘complementary’ to public intervention in the provision of services1717. Brasil. Constituição da República Federativa do Brasil de 1988. Diário Oficial da União 1988; 5 out..

What happened in the organization of healthcare in Brazil as a result of the institutional limitations defined by the 1988 Constitution? Did governmental regulation of healthcare become so significant that it merits being restrained in the form proposed by the austerity agenda?

Design of the study

The principal theoretical argumentation in this paper is that the regime of governmental financing conditions the social reach of the provision of healthcare. The notion of ‘regime’ aims to refer to the principles, laws, regulations, rules and procedures that constrain the expectations and choices of the social actors2121. Krasner SD. International Regimes. Ithaca: Cornell University Press; 1983.. It is thus considered that the magnitude of governmental expenses is an adequate indication of the condition of de-mercantilization of a national health system.

Based on the secondary information of the Health Ministry’s DATASUS and of the Federal Comptroller’s Office, this paper exemplifies the profile of Brazilian public and private expenses with data from temporal and transversal series.

The paper uses the classification categories of the WHO, which describe national health accounts. The descriptors of the WHO expenses comprise the funds that enter the health system for acquisition of goods and services financed by taxes, social security contributions, companies, civil society organizations, families or international agencies2222. Poullier JP, Hernandez P, Kawabata K. National Health Accounts. Concepts, Sources, and Methodology. Genebra: WHO; 2002.. The central categories of the national accounts of the WHO are: government expenditure – including public health insurance; and private expenditure on private health insurance and out-of-pocket expenditure.

The source for the analysis of Brazil and other economies, in terms of normative comparison, is the site http://who.int/nha/database. The health system of the central economies is taken as a normative reference to describe the Brazilian experience of de-mercantilization of health care1010. Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD). Proposal for a Taxonomy of Health Insurance. OECD Study on Private Health Insurance, OECD Health Project. June 2004. [acessado 2013 dez 23]. Disponível em: http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/24/52/31916207.pdf
http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/24/52/31916...
.

The information produced by the Brazilian Geography and Statistics Institute (Instituto Brasileiro de Geografia e Estatística, or IBGE) through the Medical Healthcare Survey (AMS), the Family Budget Survey (POF), and the National Households Sample Survey (PNAD – Health Supplement) enable us to describe the effects of the dynamics of the private sector market on the Brazilian health system. The data are analyzed by descriptive statistics.

Segmentation and focalization in healthcare

In a manner that was not anticipated by the members of the Constituent Assembly, since the late 1980s the private sector has assumed a more wide-ranging configuration than that of simply provider2323. Braga JC, Paula SG. Saúde e Previdência: Estudos de Política Social. São Paulo: Cebes/Hucitec; 1981.,2424. Bahia L. O mercado de planos e seguros de saúde no Brasil: tendências pós-regulamentação In: Negri B, Giovanni G, organizadores. Radiografia da Saúde no Brasil. Campinas: Editora Unicamp; 2001. p. 325-362. The segment of health insurance and the private healthcare plans has strengthened and established itself, favored by a low degree of regulation, tax incentives, absence of entry barriers, and exit barriers, for companies, and by the wide liberty for differentiation of contracts and provision of services2525. Lewis MA, Medici AC. Private Payers of Health Care in Brazil: characteristics, costs and coverage. Health Policy Plan 1995; 10(4):362-375.,2626. Costa NR, Castro AJW. O regime regulatório e estrutura do mercado de planos de assistência à saúde no Brasil. Regulação e Saúde. Rio de Janeiro: Agência Nacional de Saúde Suplementar; 2003..

The passing of Law 9656/1998 and the creation of the National Supplementary Health Agency (ANS) in 2000 modified the regulatory regime by setting new rules for protection of consumers, new conditions for entry and exit, and limitation of segmentation in coverage2727. Costa NR. O regime regulatório e o mercado de planos de saúde no Brasil. Cien Saude Colet 2008; 13(5):1453-1462.. Even so, the regulatory regime restricted to the health insurance industry and private health plans made it possible for companies to become stronger economically, instituting private healthcare consumption by employees with formal employment and by government workers.

It is possible to consider, then, that a new corporate standard/pattern was inaugurated in the area of healthcare in Brazil during the 1990s2828. Dias Filho PPS. Neocorporativismo e Saúde Suplementar: as bases sociais da privatização da Saúde no Brasil [tese]. Rio de Janeiro: Escola Nacional de Saúde Pública; 2016.. The segment succeeded in determining that the population occupied in the formal employment market was its preferred clientele, promoting collective plans financed by companies, to the determent of individual plans, and adopting selection of risk. The National Supplementary Health Agency has ratified companies’ strategy of selection of clientele.

In the ambit of provision of health services, the hospitals, diagnostic support services and specialized outpatient providers are used exclusively by the private clientele (individuals who have health insurance or with out-of-pocket expenditure capacity)2020. Costa NR, Vaitsman J. Universalization and Privatization: How Policy Analysis Can Help Understand the Development of Brazil’s Health System. Journal of Comparative Policy Analysis: Research and Practice 2014; 16(5):441-456.. Only in small towns do private health services have, even if only residually, a pattern of combined use by both the clientele of the SUS, clients of health plans and those who purchase medical services by out-of-pocket expenditure .

In the majority of the medium-sized and large cities, the dominant trend is distinction between (a) the services linked to health insurance or acquired by out-of-pocket expenditure, and (b) the government services of the SUS, due to the contractual rules of coverage prevented by the private market as a differential of quality of provision of service.

The institutionalization of the health reform was not sufficient to impose governmental coordination on the totality of Brazilian spending on healthcare. As Table 1 shows, since the 1990s government and private expenses have been stable. One thing that especially calls the attention is the fact that private expenditure has continued to be the larger proportion in the 1990s and 2000s, with out-of-pocket expenditure dominant. The exuberant scale of out-of-pocket expenditure on health in Brazil reflects the ambiguity of the country’s decisions in the sector, which is demonstrated below.

Table 1
Brazil - % distribution on governmental and private health expenditure – 1995 and 2008.

The unchanging relative percentages of government and private expenditure in the 1990s and 2000s is due essentially to funds being input by the municipal governments2929. Dain S. Os vários mundos do financiamento da Saúde no Brasil: uma tentativa de integração Cien Saude Colet 2007; 12(Supl.):1851-1864.. The participation of specifically municipal expenditure on healthcare underwent a significant expansion within government expenses as a whole: in 1995 the municipal percentage was 12.3%; and in 2012, it had risen to 18% of total public expenditures – while the expenditures of the state governments remained stable at around 25% of total Brazilian public expenditures on health. At the same time, there was a reduction in the proportion of the total coming from the federal government between 1995 and 2012, from 61.7% to 57%3030. Costa NR. A Estratégia de Saúde da Família, a atenção primária e o desafio das metrópoles brasileiras. Cien Saude Colet 2016; 21(5):1389-1398.. The dynamic face of the Brazilian public sector has been the development of primary care by the municipal governments3131. Macinko J, Marinho de Souza Mde F, Guanais FC, da Silva Simões CC. Going to Scale with Community-based primary care: an analysis of the family heath program and infant mortality in Brazil 1999 – 2004. Sco Sci Med 2007; 65(10):2070-2080.. Financing has ceased to be led, as a priority, by the federal Executive in recent years3030. Costa NR. A Estratégia de Saúde da Família, a atenção primária e o desafio das metrópoles brasileiras. Cien Saude Colet 2016; 21(5):1389-1398..

The activity of the Brazilian government in financing of health has, even so, federal characteristics that are not completely irrelevant: (1) incorporation of the interests that originated territorially into the decisions of the central government; (2) the high quantity, and highly heterogeneous nature, of agents focalizing regional and local ideas and interests; (3) government jurisdictions that share responsibility for formation and implementation of health policy; (4) fiscal transfer arrangements; and (5) vertical and horizontal arrangements for informal cooperation between the levels of government3232. Obinger H, Castles FG, Leibfried S. Introduction: federalism and the welfare state. In: Obinger H, Castles FG, Leibfried S, editors. Federalism and the Welfare State. New World and European Experiences. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 2006. p. 1-46.. This federal component in arrangements has a direct impact on the development and diffusion of health policy, on the scale and generosity of programs, and on the redistributive scope of the central government’s allocation of funds. The pattern of governmental development based on the municipality indicates, in this aspect, the focalization on provision of a simplified portfolio of public services mainly directed to infancy and women’s health. The SUS has been especially successful with this scope of services3333. Arretche MTS. Financiamento federal e gestão local de políticas sociais: o difícil equilíbrio entre regulação, responsabilidade e autonomia. Cien Saude Colet 2003; 8(2):331-345..

Falleti3434. Falleti TG. Infiltrating the State. The Evolution of Health Care Reforms in Brazil, 1964-1988. In: Mahoney J, Kathleen T, editors. Explaining Institutional Change: Ambiguity, Agency, and Power. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 2009. p. 38-62. argues as follows:

Brazil had some of the best-designed, most encompassing, innovative, and pro-poor social policies in Latin America. It is indeed very likely that universal health coverage and a decentralized structure that is funded with guaranteed federal transfers and that promotes users’ participation in health councils are largely responsible for the improvement of Brazil’s health outcomes. The evolution of health care reforms in Brazil shows that it is possible to break away, in a gradual and incremental manner, from the historical institutional preconditions that preclude universalization of health. They also appear to indicate that such institutional evolution leads to significantly better public health outcomes.

Studies on the impact of decentralization have, indeed, shown the positive results of healthcare activity through infant health figures over the 1990s and 2000s3535. Guanais FC, Macinko J. The Health Effects of Decentralizing Primary Care. Brazil Health Affairs 2009; 28(4):1127-1135.,3636. Victora CG, Aquino EML, Leal MC, Monteiro CA, Barros FC, Szwarcwald CL. Maternal and child health in Brazil: progress and challenges Lancet 2011; 1(377):1863-1876..

It is necessary, however, to call attention to the fact that the Brazilian central government allocates only a small portion of its financial allocation as an incentive to municipalities to develop primary care. In 2013, only 18% of the federal funds were allocated to primary care – especially for financing of the Family Health Strategy (Table 2). This is a fact that does not receive the appropriate critical treatment in the literature on health policies in Brazil, especially in literature on the field of collective health.

Table 2
Health ministry expenses in 2003 (R$ million, nominal).

The stagnation of the process of decentralization in the present decade resulted in a further 37% of federal health funding being executed in 2013 directly by the Health Ministry through the National Health Foundation, and the remaining 45% also allocated to purchasing by the central, state and municipal governments of hospitalizations, services, and high-cost medication.

If the decentralization for primary care had recognized redistributive effects at local levels3737. Costa NR, Pinto LF. Avaliação de programa de atenção à saúde: incentivo à oferta de atenção ambulatorial e a experiência da descentralização no Brasil. Cien Saude Colet 2002; 7(4):907-923., there are two considerable limitations attached to the funding distributed centrally by the Health Ministry or in which the payment decision is shared, federally:

1) The National Health Foundation allocates a considerable portion of the funding to federal hospitals in the city of Rio de Janeiro, which are functionally of little use to the SUS due to their organizational insulation. Paradoxically, decades after the implementation of the health reform, almost nothing is known about the allocation efficiency, technique, quality and equity guidelines of these hospitals.

2) The payment of specialized private and public hospitalizations and services by the Health Ministry, state governments and municipal governments has for decades been made in an inertial, and obscure, manner by a confusing web of procedures which does not favor development of any strategic guideline for guaranteeing future access and transparency in the use of the funds allocated by the Health Ministry to healthcare.

Another factor that stands out is that, even when the federal Executive places on the agenda the proposal for regionalization through Public Health Action Contracts (Contratos Organizativos da Ação Pública da Saúde, or COAPs), no new idea of governance of the use of the strategic funds is placed on the table for public consultation and decision by society3838. Brasil. Ministério da Saúde (MS). Contrato Organizativo da Ação Pública da Saúde. Brasília: MS; 2011..

Due to this deficit of governance, in these later years of the present decade the principal strategy for provision of health services of all the instances of government in the country has been the Family Health Strategy – which focused, primarily, on poor families, in all regions. In 2009, 54% of people with income of up to two times the minimum wage were registered in the Family Health Strategy, while only 16% of those with income above five times the minimum wage were registered3939. Controladoria Geral da União – Portal da Transparência. [acessado 2016 jun 1]. Disponível em: http://www.portaldatransparencia.gov.br/PortalFuncoes_Detalhe.asp?Exercicio=2013&codFuncao=10&Pagina=1
http://www.portaldatransparencia.gov.br/...
.

At the same time, in most of the large cities – with population of over 100,000 – there has been a high deficit in the supply of specialized services and diagnoses and in free distribution of medication. Also, there has been development of public hospitals and specialized services in only a few of the states of the federation4040. Instituto Brasileiro de Geografia e Estatística (IBGE). Pesquisa Nacional de Amostra de Domicílios. Rio de Janeiro: IBGE; 2010.. It is the habitual practice of state governments to take decisions which result in erratic and discontinuous supply of public emergency services, dissociated from any articulated structure of follow-up of patients and support in access to medications4141. Instituto Brasileiro de Geografia e Estatística (IBGE). POF - Pesquisa de Orçamento Familiar. Rio de Janeiro: IBGE; 2010..

Thus, the government’s policy for focus indirectly encourages development of private expenditure either out-of-pocket of through health insurance, in all the country’s income strata4040. Instituto Brasileiro de Geografia e Estatística (IBGE). Pesquisa Nacional de Amostra de Domicílios. Rio de Janeiro: IBGE; 2010.. Since the 1980s tax incentives have existed for families to acquire health insurance through direct purchase or through the intermediation of private or government employers2626. Costa NR, Castro AJW. O regime regulatório e estrutura do mercado de planos de assistência à saúde no Brasil. Regulação e Saúde. Rio de Janeiro: Agência Nacional de Saúde Suplementar; 2003..

It is also necessary to remember that, in spite of the formal responsibility of implementing and development of the SUS, the federal, state and municipal governments are also active purchasers of health insurance for government workers. In 2010 a significant proportion of all people insured by private health systems – 22.5% – was financed by the three levels of the government of the federation3939. Controladoria Geral da União – Portal da Transparência. [acessado 2016 jun 1]. Disponível em: http://www.portaldatransparencia.gov.br/PortalFuncoes_Detalhe.asp?Exercicio=2013&codFuncao=10&Pagina=1
http://www.portaldatransparencia.gov.br/...
.

In 2011, 79.5% of those insured after the creation of the ANS had a collective or corporate plan4242. Dourado DA, Elias PEM. Regionalização e Dinâmica Política do Federalismo Sanitário Brasileiro. Rev Saude Publica 2011; 45(1):204-211.. As shown by Table 3, proportions of individuals and families with private health insurance in Brazil are directly associated with family income. In 2008, the percentage of individuals with a health plan was 82.5% in the income range above five times the minimum wage – while at the other end of the scale, it was only 4.4% for families with income of up to one half of the minimum wage.

Table 3
Per capita monthly family income and proportion of private health insurance coverage – Brazil, 2003.

The significant differentiation by income group in access to the health insurance market supports a pessimistic prognosis for public policy for universalization of Brazilian healthcare, formalized in the SUS – namely that implementation of the universality of access to the SUS, without rapid expansion of the supply of public services, would lead to the population in the formal market, or those with labor union negotiation capacity, leaving the public health system1616. Faveret Filho P, Oliveira PJ. A universalização excludente: reflexões sobre as tendências do sistema de saúde. Planejamento e Políticas Públicas 1990; 3(1):139-162..

Indeed, the focusing and centralization of governmental financing in the federal government – which produces scarcity of hospital beds and specialized services – explains why the Brazilian population chooses, as preference, to leave the SUS whenever a person achieves a change in position in the income structure. The social mobility made possible by the country’s economic growth in the years 2003-2011, for example, caused a substantial increase in the number of insured families, comprising the new workers in the formal labor market who had changed income level4343. Agência Nacional de Saúde Suplementar (ANS). Dados do Setor. [acessado 2016 jun 13]. Disponível em: http://www.ans. gov.br. portal/site/dados setor/dados_setor.asp
http://www.ans. gov.br. portal/site/dado...
. This change is understandable because, on the one hand, the private insurance sector has a larger supply of specialized services and tests than the public sector (Table 4); and on the other, because the availability of use of the service network of the insurance companies and private health plans reduces exposure to the rationing found in the public sector.

Table 4
Availability of support and diagnostic establishments in the SUS and the health insurance sector – Brazil 2009.

Consultations in medical specialties, medical tests and surgeries are the main interventions that are the subject of rationing by the SUS, which imposes long waiting times on users. As an example Table 5 shows the very high delay in the SUS for provision of various types of specialized medical consultation, tests or surgeries in October 2012 in São Paulo, the country’s richest municipality. On that date, 660,000 people were on the waiting list for these procedures.

Table 5
Waiting time for specialized consultations, tests and surgery in the SUS public system in the municipality of São Paulo - October 2012.

Final considerations

Paim et al.1919. Paim J, Travassos C, Almeida C, Bahia L, Macinko J. The Brazilian health system: history, advances, and challenges. Lancet 2011; 1(377):1778 -1797. are completely right when they say that the health sector in Brazil has become dominantly private. The argument that the SUS was the result of a process of democratic mobilization is acceptable. However, the various mechanisms of participation created by the health reform did not prevent consolidation of an institutional arrangement led by the private sector2020. Costa NR, Vaitsman J. Universalization and Privatization: How Policy Analysis Can Help Understand the Development of Brazil’s Health System. Journal of Comparative Policy Analysis: Research and Practice 2014; 16(5):441-456.. Many authors already accept the uncomfortable idea that the Brazilian health sector is iniquitous and regressive in terms of families’ expenses, due to the dominant role played by out-of-pocket expenditure4444. Classe C entra em Planos de Saúde e superlota hospitais. Valor Econômico 2012; 3 dez..

Overcoming the deficit of equity in the provision of health service is still a challenge for the country. The proposal of the 1988 Constitution was an efficient solution by the political elites for the social debt in health during the redemocratization of the 1980s. It was considered that the universalizing reform for the sector would produce a systemic solution for the question of financing, access and provision of collective and individual healthcare.

The significant growth in strength of the private-sector interests in the new democracy, however, was an event that the reformers did not anticipate1515. Costa NR. Comunidade epistêmica e a formação da reforma sanitária no Brasil. Physis 2014; 24(3):809-829.. The growing focalization of provision by the SUS in the strata of lowest income in the country indicates that public action, today, carries out merely distributive functions which abdicate from the project for a wide-ranging and systemic reform of the sector. The distributive intervention of the federal government does not seek even to put in place new regulatory functions, as is seen in the health systems of the central economies, but development of public policies that are focused on and selective for the poor4545. Ugá MAD, Santos IS. An Analysis of Equity in Brazilian Health System Financing. Health Affairs 2007; 26(4):1017-1028.

The Brazilian health sector is, thus, very singular when compared to emerging countries, due to its significant participation of private healthcare insurance and the scale of out-of-pocket expenditure in its configuration2020. Costa NR, Vaitsman J. Universalization and Privatization: How Policy Analysis Can Help Understand the Development of Brazil’s Health System. Journal of Comparative Policy Analysis: Research and Practice 2014; 16(5):441-456.. Unfortunately, the development of the SUS is not the distinctive trait of the Brazilian experience in health, as Brazilian intellectual output would have us believe. There is no doubt that the combination of focalization of primary healthcare on the poorest strata, with the practice of risk selection by the health insurance companies and health plans, imposes the burden of out-of-pocket expenditure as the solution for those who need healthcare at all levels of complexity. The evidence of the waiting list proves that the population is not being served in the area of health, in spite of the institutional orientation for universal and free services in Brazil. With such a large scale of systemic deregulation, we submit that the governmental failings in provision of healthcare will not be overcome only with the silver bullet of austerity, as the thinking of Brazilian liberal economists supposes.

References

  • 1
    Ames B. Os entraves da democracia no Brasil: uma crise antevista? Folha de S. Paulo 2016 maio 13.
  • 2
    Lisboa M. Entrevista. Valor Econômico 2016 jun 23; p. 8.
  • 3
    Arrow KJ. Uncertainty and the Welfare Economics of Medical Care. American Economic Review 1963; 53(5):941-973.
  • 4
    Hsiao W. Comparing Health Care Systems: What Nations Can Learn from One Another. Journal of Health Politics, Policy and Law 1992; 17(4):613-636.
  • 5
    Hsiao W, Heller PS. What Should Macroeconomists Know about Health Care Policy? IMF Working Papers 2013.
  • 6
    Xu K, Evans DB, Kawabata K, Zeramdini R, Klavus J, Murray CJ. Household catastrophic health expenditure: a multicountry analysis. Lancet 2003; 362(9378):111-117.
  • 7
    Castro JD. Regulação em saúde: análise de conceitos fundamentais. Sociologias 2002; 1(7):122-135.
  • 8
    Esping-Anderser G. As Três Economias Políticas do Welfare State. Lua Nova 1991; 1(24):85-115.
  • 9
    Moran M. Understanding the welfare state: the case of health care British Journal of Politics and International Relations 2000; 2(2):135-160.
  • 10
    Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD). Proposal for a Taxonomy of Health Insurance. OECD Study on Private Health Insurance, OECD Health Project. June 2004. [acessado 2013 dez 23]. Disponível em: http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/24/52/31916207.pdf
    » http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/24/52/31916207.pdf
  • 11
    Savedoff WD, de Ferranti D, Smith AL, Fan V. Political and economic aspects of the transition to universal health coverage. Lancet 2012; 380(9845):924-932.
  • 12
    Schmitter PC. Still the Century of Corporatism? The Review of Politics 1974; 36(1):85-131
  • 13
    Costa NR. Estudo de Caso: México. In: Biasoto G, Silva PLB, Dain S, organizadores. Regulação do Setor Saúde nas Américas: As Relações Entre o Público e o Privado. Brasília: Organização Panamericana de Saúde, Agência Nacional de Saúde Suplementar; 2006. p. 375-392.
  • 14
    Weyland K. Social Movements and the State: The Politics of Health Reform in Brazil. World Development 1995; 23(10):1699-1712.
  • 15
    Costa NR. Comunidade epistêmica e a formação da reforma sanitária no Brasil. Physis 2014; 24(3):809-829.
  • 16
    Faveret Filho P, Oliveira PJ. A universalização excludente: reflexões sobre as tendências do sistema de saúde. Planejamento e Políticas Públicas 1990; 3(1):139-162.
  • 17
    Brasil. Constituição da República Federativa do Brasil de 1988. Diário Oficial da União 1988; 5 out.
  • 18
    Draibe SM. Há Tendências e Tendências: Com que Estado de Bem Estar Social Haveremos de Conviver? Cadernos de Pesquisa NEPP Unicamp 1989; 1(10):1-89.
  • 19
    Paim J, Travassos C, Almeida C, Bahia L, Macinko J. The Brazilian health system: history, advances, and challenges. Lancet 2011; 1(377):1778 -1797.
  • 20
    Costa NR, Vaitsman J. Universalization and Privatization: How Policy Analysis Can Help Understand the Development of Brazil’s Health System. Journal of Comparative Policy Analysis: Research and Practice 2014; 16(5):441-456.
  • 21
    Krasner SD. International Regimes Ithaca: Cornell University Press; 1983.
  • 22
    Poullier JP, Hernandez P, Kawabata K. National Health Accounts. Concepts, Sources, and Methodology Genebra: WHO; 2002.
  • 23
    Braga JC, Paula SG. Saúde e Previdência: Estudos de Política Social São Paulo: Cebes/Hucitec; 1981.
  • 24
    Bahia L. O mercado de planos e seguros de saúde no Brasil: tendências pós-regulamentação In: Negri B, Giovanni G, organizadores. Radiografia da Saúde no Brasil Campinas: Editora Unicamp; 2001. p. 325-362
  • 25
    Lewis MA, Medici AC. Private Payers of Health Care in Brazil: characteristics, costs and coverage. Health Policy Plan 1995; 10(4):362-375.
  • 26
    Costa NR, Castro AJW. O regime regulatório e estrutura do mercado de planos de assistência à saúde no Brasil. Regulação e Saúde Rio de Janeiro: Agência Nacional de Saúde Suplementar; 2003.
  • 27
    Costa NR. O regime regulatório e o mercado de planos de saúde no Brasil. Cien Saude Colet 2008; 13(5):1453-1462.
  • 28
    Dias Filho PPS. Neocorporativismo e Saúde Suplementar: as bases sociais da privatização da Saúde no Brasil [tese]. Rio de Janeiro: Escola Nacional de Saúde Pública; 2016.
  • 29
    Dain S. Os vários mundos do financiamento da Saúde no Brasil: uma tentativa de integração Cien Saude Colet 2007; 12(Supl.):1851-1864.
  • 30
    Costa NR. A Estratégia de Saúde da Família, a atenção primária e o desafio das metrópoles brasileiras. Cien Saude Colet 2016; 21(5):1389-1398.
  • 31
    Macinko J, Marinho de Souza Mde F, Guanais FC, da Silva Simões CC. Going to Scale with Community-based primary care: an analysis of the family heath program and infant mortality in Brazil 1999 – 2004. Sco Sci Med 2007; 65(10):2070-2080.
  • 32
    Obinger H, Castles FG, Leibfried S. Introduction: federalism and the welfare state. In: Obinger H, Castles FG, Leibfried S, editors. Federalism and the Welfare State. New World and European Experiences Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 2006. p. 1-46.
  • 33
    Arretche MTS. Financiamento federal e gestão local de políticas sociais: o difícil equilíbrio entre regulação, responsabilidade e autonomia. Cien Saude Colet 2003; 8(2):331-345.
  • 34
    Falleti TG. Infiltrating the State. The Evolution of Health Care Reforms in Brazil, 1964-1988. In: Mahoney J, Kathleen T, editors. Explaining Institutional Change: Ambiguity, Agency, and Power Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 2009. p. 38-62.
  • 35
    Guanais FC, Macinko J. The Health Effects of Decentralizing Primary Care. Brazil Health Affairs 2009; 28(4):1127-1135.
  • 36
    Victora CG, Aquino EML, Leal MC, Monteiro CA, Barros FC, Szwarcwald CL. Maternal and child health in Brazil: progress and challenges Lancet 2011; 1(377):1863-1876.
  • 37
    Costa NR, Pinto LF. Avaliação de programa de atenção à saúde: incentivo à oferta de atenção ambulatorial e a experiência da descentralização no Brasil. Cien Saude Colet 2002; 7(4):907-923.
  • 38
    Brasil. Ministério da Saúde (MS). Contrato Organizativo da Ação Pública da Saúde Brasília: MS; 2011.
  • 39
    Controladoria Geral da União – Portal da Transparência. [acessado 2016 jun 1]. Disponível em: http://www.portaldatransparencia.gov.br/PortalFuncoes_Detalhe.asp?Exercicio=2013&codFuncao=10&Pagina=1
    » http://www.portaldatransparencia.gov.br/PortalFuncoes_Detalhe.asp?Exercicio=2013&codFuncao=10&Pagina=1
  • 40
    Instituto Brasileiro de Geografia e Estatística (IBGE). Pesquisa Nacional de Amostra de Domicílios Rio de Janeiro: IBGE; 2010.
  • 41
    Instituto Brasileiro de Geografia e Estatística (IBGE). POF - Pesquisa de Orçamento Familiar Rio de Janeiro: IBGE; 2010.
  • 42
    Dourado DA, Elias PEM. Regionalização e Dinâmica Política do Federalismo Sanitário Brasileiro. Rev Saude Publica 2011; 45(1):204-211.
  • 43
    Agência Nacional de Saúde Suplementar (ANS). Dados do Setor. [acessado 2016 jun 13]. Disponível em: http://www.ans. gov.br. portal/site/dados setor/dados_setor.asp
    » http://www.ans. gov.br. portal/site/dados setor/dados_setor.asp
  • 44
    Classe C entra em Planos de Saúde e superlota hospitais. Valor Econômico 2012; 3 dez.
  • 45
    Ugá MAD, Santos IS. An Analysis of Equity in Brazilian Health System Financing. Health Affairs 2007; 26(4):1017-1028
  • 46
    Hunter W, Sugiyama NB. Democracy and Social Policy in Brazil: Advancing Basic Needs, Preserving Privilege Interests. Latin American Politics and Society 2009; 51(2):29-58.

Publication Dates

  • Publication in this collection
    Apr 2017

History

  • Received
    29 May 2016
  • Reviewed
    04 Aug 2016
  • Accepted
    11 Oct 2016
ABRASCO - Associação Brasileira de Saúde Coletiva Rio de Janeiro - RJ - Brazil
E-mail: revscol@fiocruz.br